23 Feb 2021 3 min read

Inflation: money and the new supply-side economics

By Alex Mack , Christopher Jeffery

It’s not an imminent concern, but eventually central banks may be surprised by how much they have to do to control inflation.

 

dollar-chart-stock.jpg

Last week, the US retail sales numbers for January smashed forecasts and once again showed that stimulus works, especially direct cash payments to households. Around 25% of the $600 received by individuals earning $75,000 or less was immediately spent, generating a $30 billion bounce in retail sales across all categories.

While this news broke, debate continued in Congress about the next round of stimulus. Treasury Secretary Janet Yellen commented that “the risk of doing too little is greater than of doing too much”.

If such an approach is adopted, the direct uplift to household incomes will potentially be at least three times larger than included in the COVID-19 relief bill at the end of 2020. This money should hit people’s accounts just as the US begins to re-open more fully. Alongside the excess household savings accumulated during the pandemic, this could fuel a surge in demand.

This makes us think about the implications of the money supply glut. None of us have seen money supply grow on the current scale, the only precedent being during the Second World War.

Half of the increase in broad money supply sits directly in household accounts. We believe that a significant amount of this cash will be spent rather than kept in reserve, boosting growth, corporate profitability, and possibly inflation.

All about that base effect

On inflation, we know there will be a pronounced base effect around the spring as prices fell sharply at the equivalent point of 2020 when the economy was locked down. This, plus later boosts from CPI components that were depressed by restrictions like airfares and hotel prices, could temporarily raise inflation above target-consistent levels.

The Federal Reserve has highlighted this potential outcome, with January’s meeting minutes containing a discussion on why it would be prudent to look through this increase.

This makes sense, in our view, as it is equally likely that inflation will fall back in the summer. Base effects do reverse, and there are also some aspects of inflation that have been lifted by the pandemic but are likely to weaken once the economy reopens. Used-car prices are one example.

Further out, the inflation picture becomes much murkier. How much slack will be left in the economy? Does the jump in money supply matter? Are some of the structural disinflationary forces of the past decade, like technology, beginning to shift? How well anchored are inflation expectations?

We believe that inflation becoming high enough to constrain monetary policy is still a way off. But if we get there, central banks in developed markets might be surprised by how much they have to raise rates to reduce inflationary pressure.

Why would they be surprised? First, money doesn’t play a role in their models. As former Federal Reserve Governor Larry Meyer said in 2001, “Money plays no explicit role in today’s consensus macro model, and it plays virtually no role in the conduct of monetary policy.” This is despite monetary aggregates generally being excellent predictors of some key economic metrics, particularly in the Eurozone and China.

Second, they aren’t able to directly undo the monetary and fiscal one-two that’s been so effective at putting cash in consumers’ pockets. For that, the fiscal authorities need to help them take back some of the excess. That’s not historically the strong point of a political process that operates on a short-term electoral cycle.

Alex Mack

Fund Manager, Active Fixed Income

Alex is a Fund Manager in the Active Fixed Income team. Alex joined LGIM in 2013 as a graduate. Alex holds an MPhil in Economics from the University of Cambridge, St Catharine’s College, and a BEconSc in Economics from Manchester University. Alex also holds the IMC.

Alex Mack

Christopher Jeffery

Head of Inflation and Rates Strategy

Chris works as a strategist within LGIM’s asset allocation team, focussing on discretionary fixed income and systematic risk premia strategies. He coordinates global rates and inflation strategy across LGIM’s asset allocation and fixed income capabilities. He joined LGIM in 2014 from BNP Paribas Investment Partners where he worked as a senior economist and strategist within the Multi-Asset Solutions group. Prior to that, he worked as an economist within monetary analysis at the Bank of England with a focus on the UK domestic economy. Chris graduated from University College, Oxford in 2001 with a first class degree in philosophy, politics and economics. He also holds an Msc in economics (research) from the London School of Economics and is a CFA charterholder.

Christopher Jeffery